next up previous
Next: About this document Up: Appendix Previous: Appendix

Conditions for oscillations

A most general characteristic equation can be deduced from:

where x and y are the deviations from equilibrium values and A,B,C,D the coefficents of the linear expansion of the dynamical system. The characteristic equation in is then:

and the discriminant:

Oscillations occur when the discriminant is negative. A necessary condition is that BC<0. An interpretation of the fact that couplings should be larger than diagonal terms is that the system should be "truly" 2-dimensional. Otherwise the "fast" variable simply follows the "slow" variable decay towards equilibrium.

subsection Analysis of Variable Prices

Here we present the analysis for the case described in Section 4, of prices with a lower bound.

Suppose that prices time are given by equation 39 with , so that prices decrease from a maximum of toward a minimum of . In order to make comparisons with the results of the other sections, a reasonable assumption is that the minimum price is lower than under the constant price regime of section 2, i.e. that , where is the price of section 2. Using equation 39 implies that there is no limit on the income from selling the harvest, as there is when a=0. However,as long as a is small compared to 1, we expect that the results given for the a=0 case will essentially hold: namely that a nonzero equilibrium only exists when b is above a minimum value near , and that (when ) the equilibrium resource level is larger, the equilibrium is more strongly attracting, and oscillations are less likely than in the constant price case. However, as a moves away from zero and price supports become stronger, we would like to know how this affects the a=0 results.

When a > 0 the nonzero equilibrium of the nondimensionalized system with , (, given by equation 5) is , , where

 

and we define , , and .

As we found in section 4, adding prices does not change the equilibrium capital but significantly affects the equilibrium resource. However, unlike the a=0 case, N-p is positive for all positive values of b. What is different now is that if b<1 then as while if b>1 then approaches the a=0 value as .

Letting

 

and linearizing about the nontrivial equilibrium, we find that the eigenvalues of this system are:

 

These eigenvalues always have negative real part. This can be seen via the following argument. Note that in the remaining discussion of this section, we drop the tildes. Since , these eigenvalues both have negative real part when . Using the relationship between a, b, c and to replace each , this condition on can be rewritten as

 

or

 

and applying the equality again shows that this is always true. Thus this is always a stable equilibrium point. It is a stable spiral point when

 

In the limit as , these results approach those found in section 3. We expect that increasing a will have the effect of annuling the impact of decreasing prices, and, in fact, increasing the lower bound on prices, , decreases the equilibrium level of the resource, . However, the dependence of the eigenvalues on a is much more subtle, and depends on the values of b and c. For very small a, the upper bound on for oscillations decreases as a increases (when satisfies the constraint ), implying a stabilizing effect. When the parameters are such that satisfies this inequality and the value under the square root is negative, then the real part of increases in magnitude with a when 1 < b < 3, and otherwise decreases.

These results are found by the following calculations:

 

which is negative for all a>0.

 

and

 



next up previous
Next: About this document Up: Appendix Previous: Appendix



weisbuch
Fri Feb 7 13:18:37 GMT+0100 1997